+ - 0:00:00
Notes for current slide
Notes for next slide

1.4 — Preferences and Utility

ECON 306 • Microeconomic Analysis • Fall 2020

Ryan Safner
Assistant Professor of Economics
safner@hood.edu
ryansafner/microF20
microF20.classes.ryansafner.com

Consumer's Objectives

  • What do consumers want? What do they maximize?

  • Avoid being normative & make as few assumptions as possible

  • We'll assume people maximize preferences

    • WTF does that mean?

Preferences

Preferences I

  • Which bundles of (x,y) are preferred over others?

Example:

a=(412) or b=(612)

Preferences II

  • We will allow three possible answers:

Preferences II

  • We will allow three possible answers:
  1. ab: Strictly prefer a over b

Preferences II

  • We will allow three possible answers:
  1. ab: Strictly prefer a over b

  2. ab: Strictly prefer b over a

Preferences II

  • We will allow three possible answers:
  1. ab: Strictly prefer a over b

  2. ab: Strictly prefer b over a

  3. ab: Indifferent between a and b

Preferences II

  • We will allow three possible answers:
  1. ab: Strictly prefer a over b

  2. ab: Strictly prefer b over a

  3. ab: Indifferent between a and b

  • Preferences are a list of all such comparisons between all bundles

See appendix in today's class page for more.

Indifference Curves

Mapping Preferences Graphically I

  • For each bundle, we now have 3 pieces of information:

    • amount of x
    • amount of y
    • preference compared to other bundles
  • How to represent this information graphically?

Mapping Preferences Graphically II

  • Cartographers have the answer for us

  • On a map, contour lines link areas of equal height

  • We will use "indifference curves" to link bundles of equal preference

Mapping Preferences Graphically III

2-D Indifference Curve Contours

Indifference Curves: Example

Example: Suppose you are hunting for an apartment. You value both the size of the apartment and the number of friends that live nearby.

Indifference Curves: Example

Example: Suppose you are hunting for an apartment. You value both the size of the apartment and the number of friends that live nearby.

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2

Indifference Curves: Example

Example: Suppose you are hunting for an apartment. You value both the size of the apartment and the number of friends that live nearby.

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2
    • Apartments that are larger and/or have more friends A

Indifference Curves: Example

Example: Suppose you are hunting for an apartment. You value both the size of the apartment and the number of friends that live nearby.

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2
    • Apartments that are larger and/or have more friends A
    • Apartments that are smaller and/or have fewer friends A

Indifference Curves: Example

Example:

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2

  • Apt. B has more friends but less ft2

Indifference Curves: Example

Example:

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2

  • Apt. B has more friends but less ft2

  • Apt. C has still more friends but less ft2

Indifference Curves: Example

Example:

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2

  • Apt. B has more friends but less ft2

  • Apt. C has still more friends but less ft2

  • If ABC, on same indifference curve

Indifference Curves: Example

  • Indifferent between all apartments on the same curve

Indifference Curves: Example

  • Indifferent between all apartments on the same curve

  • Apts above curve are preferred over apts on curve

    • DABC
    • On a higher curve

Indifference Curves: Example

  • Indifferent between all apartments on the same curve

  • Apts above curve are preferred over apts on curve

    • DABC
    • On a higher curve
  • Apts below curve are less preferred than apts on curve
    • EABC
    • On a lower curve

Curves Never Cross!

  • Indifference curves can never cross: preferences are transitive
    • If I prefer AB, and BC, I must prefer AC

Curves Never Cross!

  • Indifference curves can never cross: preferences are transitive

    • If I prefer AB, and BC, I must prefer AC
  • Suppose two curves crossed:

    • AB
    • BC
    • But C B!
    • Preferences are not transitive!

Marginal Rate of Substitution

Marginal Rate of Substitution I

  • If I take away one friend nearby, how many more ft2 would you need to keep you indifferent?

Marginal Rate of Substitution I

  • If I take away one friend nearby, how many more ft2 would you need to keep you indifferent?

  • Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS): rate at which you trade off one good for the other and remain indifferent

  • Think of this as your opportunity cost: # of units of y you need to give up to acquire 1 more x

MRS vs. Budget Constraint Slope

  • Budget constraint (slope) measured the market's tradeoff between x and y based on market prices

  • MRS measures your personal evaluation of x vs. y based on your preferences

  • Foreshadowing: what if they are different? Are you truly maximizing your preferences?

Marginal Rate of Substitution II

  • MRS is the slope of the indifference curve MRSx,y=ΔyΔx=riserun

  • Amount of y given up for 1 more x

  • Note: slope (MRS) changes along the curve!

Utility

So Where are the Numbers?

  • Long ago (1890s), utility considered a real, measurable, cardinal scale

  • Utility thought to be lurking in people's brains

    • Could be understood from first principles: calories, water, warmth, etc
  • Obvious problems

"Neuroeconomics" & cognitive scientists are re-attempting a scientific approach to measure utility

Utility Functions?

  • 20th century innovation: preferences as the objects of maximization

  • We can plausibly measure preferences via implications of peoples' actions!

  • Principle of Revealed Preference: if x and y are both feasible, and if x is chosen over y, then the person must (weakly) prefer xy

  • Flawless? Of course not. But extremely useful!

Utility Functions! I

  • So how can we build a function to "maximize preferences"?

  • Construct a utility function u() that represents preference relations (,,)

  • Assign utility numbers to bundles, such that, for any bundles a and b: abu(a)>u(b)

The is a placeholder for whatever goods we are considering (e.g. x, y, burritos, lattes, etc)

Utility Functions! II

  • We can model "as if" the consumer is maximizing utility/preferences by maximizing the utility function:

  • "Maximizing preferences": choosing a such that ab for all available b

  • "Maximizing utility": choosing a such that u(a)>u(b) for all available b

  • Identical if they contain the same information

Utility Functions, Pural I

  • Imagine three alternative bundles of (x,y): a=(1,2)b=(2,2)c=(4,3)

Utility Functions, Pural I

  • Imagine three alternative bundles of (x,y): a=(1,2)b=(2,2)c=(4,3)
  • Create a utility function u() that assigns each bundle a utility level of
u()
u(a)=1
u(b)=2
u(c)=3

Utility Functions, Pural I

  • Imagine three alternative bundles of (x,y): a=(1,2)b=(2,2)c=(4,3)
  • Create a utility function u() that assigns each bundle a utility level of
u()
u(a)=1
u(b)=2
u(c)=3
  • Does it mean that bundle c is 3 times the utility of a?

Utility Functions, Pural II

  • Imagine three alternative bundles of (x,y): a=(1,2)b=(2,2)c=(4,3)
  • Now consider u() and a second utility function v():
u() v()
u(a)=1 v(a)=3
u(b)=2 v(b)=5
u(c)=3 v(c)=7

Utility Functions, Pural III

  • Utility numbers have an ordinal meaning only, not cardinal

    • Only the ordering cba matters!
  • Both are valid:

    • u(c)>u(b)>u(a)
    • v(c)>v(b)>v(a)

See the Mathematical Appendix in Today's Class Page for why.

Utility Functions and Indifference Curves I

  • Two tools to represent preferences: indifference curves and utility functions

  • Indifference curve: all equally preferred bundles same utility level

  • Each indifference curve represents one level (or contour) of utility surface (function)

Utility Functions and Indifference Curves II

2-D Indifference Curve Contours: y=u2x

Marginal Utility

MRS and Marginal Utility I

  • Recall: marginal rate of substitution MRSx,y is slope of the indifference curve

    • Amount of y given up for 1 more x
  • How to calculate MRS?

    • Recall it changes (not a straight line)!
    • We can calculate it using something from the utility function

MRS and Marginal Utility II

  • Marginal utility: change in utility from a marginal increase in consumption

MRS and Marginal Utility II

  • Marginal utility: change in utility from a marginal increase in consumption

Marginal utility of x: MUx=Δu(x,y)Δx

MRS and Marginal Utility II

  • Marginal utility: change in utility from a marginal increase in consumption

Marginal utility of x: MUx=Δu(x,y)Δx

Marginal utility of y: MUy=Δu(x,y)Δy

MRS and Marginal Utility II

  • Marginal utility: change in utility from a marginal increase in consumption

  • Math (calculus): "marginal" means "derivative with respect to"

    • I will always derive marginal utility functions for you

MRS and Marginal Utility: Example

Example: For an example utility function

u(x,y)=x2+y3

  • Marginal utility of x: MUx=2x
  • Marginal utlity of y: MUy=3y2

MRS Equation and Marginal Utility

  • Relationship between MU and MRS:

ΔyΔxMRS=MUxMUy

MRS and Preferences

MRS and Preferences: Goods, Bads, Neutrals

  • More precise ways to classify objects:

  • A good enters utility function positively

    • good utility
    • Willing to pay (give up other goods) to acquire more (monotonic)

MRS and Preferences: Goods, Bads, Neutrals

  • More precise ways to classify objects:

  • A good enters utility function positively

    • good utility
    • Willing to pay (give up other goods) to acquire more (monotonic)
  • A bad enters utility function negatively

    • good utility
    • Willing to pay (give up other goods) to get rid of

MRS and Preferences: Goods, Bads, Neutrals

  • More precise ways to classify objects:

  • A neutral does not enter utility function at all

    • , has no effect on utility

MRS and Preferences: Substitutes

Example: Consider 1-Liter bottles of coke and 2-Liter bottles of coke

  • Always willing to substitute between Two 1-L bottles for One 2-L bottle

  • Perfect substitutes: goods that can be substituted at same fixed rate and yield same utility

  • MRS1L,2L=0.5 (a constant!)

MRS and Preferences: Complements

Example: Consider hot dogs and hot dog buns

  • Always consume together in fixed proportions (in this case, 1 for 1)

  • Perfect complements: goods that can be consumed together in same fixed proportion and yield same utility

  • MRSH,B= ?

Cobb-Douglas Utility Functions

  • A very common functional form in economics is Cobb-Douglas

u(x,y)=xayb

  • Where a,b>0 (and very often a+b=1)
  • Extremely useful, you will see it often!
    • Strictly convex and monotonic indifference curves
    • Other nice properties (we'll see later)
    • See the appendix in today's class page

Practice

Example: Suppose you can consume apples (a) and broccoli (b), and earn utility according to: u(a,b)=2ab

Where your marginal utilities are:

MUa=2bMUb=2a

  1. Put a on the horizontal axis and b on the vertical axis. Write an equation for MRSa,b.

  2. Would bundles of (1,4) and (2,2) be on the same indifference curve?

Paused

Help

Keyboard shortcuts

, , Pg Up, k Go to previous slide
, , Pg Dn, Space, j Go to next slide
Home Go to first slide
End Go to last slide
Number + Return Go to specific slide
b / m / f Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode
c Clone slideshow
p Toggle presenter mode
t Restart the presentation timer
?, h Toggle this help
Esc Back to slideshow