Markets are great when:
If any of these conditions are not met, we have market failure
Markets are great when:
If any of these conditions are not met, we have market failure
The static benefits of markets all come from markets being in equilibrium:
But don’t forget the dynamic benefits of markets as a discovery process! (class 3.3)
To reach equilibrium, market prices need to be able to adjust
There are unrealized gains from trade that exist in disequilibrium (shaded)
If market prices are prevented from adjusting, shortage/surplus becomes permanent
Lost CS and/or PS: Deadweight loss (DWL)
Various government policies can prevent markets from equilibrating & create DWL:
† Some may be necessary (taxes fund government), but create market inefficiencies.
The toilet paper aisle of my Giant grocery store, March 2020
Where did all of the ... go?
Three major issues:
More individuals want to buy more of the good at every price
Demand increases, becomes less elastic
More individuals want to buy more of the good at every price
Demand increases, becomes less elastic
At the original market price, a shortage! (qD>qS)
More individuals want to buy more of the good at every price
Demand increases, becomes less elastic
At the original market price, a shortage! (qD>qS)
Sellers are supplying Q1, but some buyers willing to pay more for Q1
More individuals want to buy more of the good at every price
Demand increases, becomes less elastic
At the original market price, a shortage! (qD>qS)
Sellers are supplying Q1, but some buyers willing to pay more for Q1
Buyers raise bids, inducing sellers to sell more
Reach new equilibrium with:
It might that supply is very inelastic
Suppliers can’t produce and sell more units even if they want to at very high price demanded
Thus, the new high price is an equilibrium that will persist for a while
Additionally, government has anti-price-gouging laws, a price ceiling at the original price, P1
Qd>Qs: excess demand, a shortage!
Sellers will not supply more than Q1 at price ¯P1
Additionally, government has anti-price-gouging laws, a price ceiling at the original price, P1
Qd>Qs: excess demand, a shortage!
Sellers will not supply more than Q1 at price ¯P1
For Q1 units, buyers are willing to pay PD!
If prices were allowed to adjust: buyers would bid higher prices to get the scarce Qs goods
Sellers would respond to rising willingness to pay, and produce and sell more
But the price is not allowed to rise above ¯P1!
Official price is ˉP, sellers gain monetary revenues
Competition exists between buyers to obtain scarce Qs goods
Goods are distributed by non-market means:
Economic rents: excess resturns (above cost) go to those who own & distribute the scarce goods
A relatively high price:
Conveys information: good is relatively scarce
Creates incentives for:
"The Canadian National Post, citing the Canadian Food Inspection Agency, says that 'There are no shortages or disruptions to [food] production, importation or export,' and that 'the shelves remain stocked.' ... 'A price surge as a result of natural market forces is not something that is regulated by Canadian competition laws or otherwise. Canada’s competition laws generally don’t interfere with the free market.' ... Canadians will have enough food to eat. But it will be more expensive.
A supermarket in Denmark got tired of people hoarding hand sanitizer, so came up with their own way of stopping it.
— Birger (@Birger_s) March 18, 2020
1 bottle kr40 (€5.50)
2 bottles kr1000 (€134.00) each bottle.
Hoarding stopped!#COVID19 #Hoarding pic.twitter.com/eKTabEjScc (via @_schuermann) cc @svenseele
"As the nation’s economy and health-care system struggle to adjust to the pandemic, more and more states are reexamining some of their oldest occupational and business regulations—rules that, although couched as protecting consumers, do far more to limit competition...While some states have ordered their occupational-licensing boards to speed up the licensure of new health-care practitioners, others...are granting immediate licensing reciprocity to any practitioner licensed in any state...Even Florida, which has long jealously guarded its occupational-licensing regime to prevent semiretired snowbirds from poaching on the locals’ turf, [is] allowing out-of-state health-care providers to practice telemedicine in the state without a license."
"Illinois has waived licensure fees for retired medical practitioners who wish to resume practice. Oklahoma and Massachusetts have eliminated restrictions that required doctors to have a preexisting doctor-patient relationship before they could offer telemedicine services."
"Also being reexamined are state certificate-of-need, or CON, laws. A product of 1970s-era economic regulation, CON laws require health-care providers to prove that new services are “needed” before they may purchase certain large equipment, open new or expanded facilities, or—as is crucial now—offer home health-care services. Often, these laws give an effective veto power to existing medical providers, allowing them to torpedo new competition for their own benefit...Basic economics predicts that competition reduces prices for consumers, and occupational licensing works directly to stifle competition."
"The University of Minnesota economist Morris Kleiner, a leading researcher on occupational licensing, estimates that licensing costs consumers nearly $200 billion annually. This might be justifiable if licensing produced substantial improvements in quality, yet most research has failed to find a connection between licensure and service quality or safety."
How did the U.S. government only manage to produce a fraction as many testing kits as its peer countries? There have been three major regulatory barriers so far to scaling up testing by public labs and private companies: 1) obtaining an Emergency Use Authorization (EUA); 2) being certified to perform high-complexity testing consistent with requirements under Clinical Laboratory Improvement Amendments (CLIA);...
...and 3) complying with the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act (HIPAA) Privacy Rule and the Common Rule related to the protection of human research subjects. On the demand side, narrow restrictions on who qualified for testing prevented the U.S. from adequately using what capacity it did have.
The Knowledge Problem: How to coordinate the tacit, fragmented knowledge of opportunities and conditions dispersed across millions of individuals (and accessible to none in total) in order to maximize the ability of individuals to achieve their goals
The Knowledge Problem: How to coordinate the tacit, fragmented knowledge of opportunities and conditions dispersed across millions of individuals (and accessible to none in total) in order to maximize the ability of individuals to achieve their goals
The Incentives Problem: How to structure incentives that individuals face in a way that maximizes cooperative behavior (voluntary exchange and association) and minimizes non-cooperative behavior (cheating, opportunism, exploitation, violence, rent-seeking)
No system is perfect
We need to find arrangements that are robust to knowledge & incentive problems
Easy (unpersuasive) case: perfect information & pure benevolence
Hard (persuasive) case: uncertainty & selfish behavior
Treat people as they are: sometimes good, bad, smart, stupid, opportunistic, altruistic, depending on the institutions they face!
People often recommend optimal policies as if they could be installed by a benevolent dictator
In reality, 1st-best policies are distorted by the knowledge problem, the incentives problem, and politics
Compare imperfections of feasible and relevant alternative systems
Economics: think on the margin!
Adam Smith
1723-1790
“[Though] he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention...By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it,” (Book IV, Chapter 2.9).
Smith, Adam, 1776, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
“[Though] he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention...By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it,” (Book IV, Chapter 2.9).
Smith, Adam, 1776, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
"[Though] he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention...By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it," (Book IV, Chapter 2.9).
Smith, Adam, 1776, An Enquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
Douglass C. North
1920-2015
Economics Nobel 1993
“Institutions are the humanly devised constraints that structure political economic and social interaction. They consist of both informal constraints (sanctions, taboos, customs, traditions, and codes of conduct), and formal rules (constitutions, laws, property rights),” (p.10)
“Institutions are the rules of the game in a society,” (p.1).
North, Douglass C, (1991), "Institutions," Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(1): 97-112.
North, Douglass C, (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance
“Who needs this nail?”
“Don't worry about it! The main thing is that we immediately fulfilled the plan for nails!”
“Dear customer, in the leather goods department of our store, a shipment of 500 imported womens' purses has been recieved. Four hundred and fifty of them have been bought by employees of the store. Fourty-nine are under the counter and have been ordered in advance for friends. One purse is in the display window. We invite you to visit the leather department to buy this purse!” (p.38).
White, Lawrence H, 2012, The Clash of Economic Ideas, pp.38-9
“Society” is not a choosing-agent or an optimization problem
Individuals have different interests in their different social capacities
Learn more in my Public Economics course
Voters express preferences through elections
Special interest groups provide additional information and advocacy for lawmaking
Politicians create laws reflecting voter and interest gorup preferences
Bureaucrats implement laws according to goals set by politicians
Voters express preferences through elections
Voters as economic agents:
Choose: < a candidate >
In order to maximize: < utility >
Subject to: < constraints? >
Citizens vote in politicians to enact various laws that citizens prefer -- and vote politicians out of office if they fail to deliver
A collective action problem: citizens need to monitor the performance of politicians and bureaucrats to ensure government serves voters' interests
Voting is instrumental in enacting voters' preferences into policy
Good governance is a public good: an individual citizen enjoys small fraction of benefit created
Additionally, policies & elections depend on many millions of people
Individual bears a private cost of informing self and participating
Hence, a free-rider problem
A rational individual will vote iff: p(B)+W>C
B: perceived net benefits of candidate X over Y
p≈0
B is a public good
C>0
A rational individual will vote iff: p(B)+W>C
If citizens are purely rational, W=0
Citizens then vote if p(B)>C
Prediction: rational citizen does not vote
Year | Turnout of Elligible Voters |
---|---|
2016 | 55.7% |
2012 | 54.9% |
2008 | 58.2% |
2004 | 55.7% |
2000 | 50.3% |
1996 | 49.0% |
1992 | 55.2% |
Sources: Wikipedia, U.S. Census Bureau, Bipartisan Policy Center
A rational individual will vote iff: p(B)+W>C
Now suppose, D>0
Citizens then vote if D>C
More importantly, the voter votes regardless of the positions of the candidates!
Vote for non-rational reasons: "more presidential looking," "taller," "a better temperament," etc.
Many do vote, even at significant personal cost!
"Expressive voting": people vote to express identity, solidarity, tribalism, preferences, etc
Voting as a pure consumption good, not an instrumental investment to achieve policy preferences
Model predicts rational ignorance
Not necessarily no voting, but
Winston Churchill
1874-1965
"The best argument against democracy is a five minute conversation with the average voter."
Somin, Ilya, 2014, Democracy and Political Ignorance
Somin, Ilya, 2014, Democracy and Political Ignorance
Special interest groups: any group of individuals that value a common cause
SIGs as economic agents:
Choose: < a candidate to support >
In order to maximize: < utility >
Subject to: < budget >
But power and influence is not evenly distributed across interest groups
Logic of collective action: Smaller and more homogenous groups face lower collective action costs of organizing than larger and more heterogeneous groups
Smaller groups to whom benefit (cost) of a policy is more concentrated can outmobilize larger groups where benefit (cost) is more dispersed
Politicians create laws reflecting voter and interest gorup preferences
The politician's problem:
Choose: < a platform >
In order to maximize: < votes >
Subject to: < being re/elected >
Rationally ignorant voters pay little attention to actual substance or policy-making; more to TV-friendly spectacles
Big speeches, ribbon cutting ceremonies, attack ads on rivals, etc
Platforms more about broad platitudes than substance "family values," "tough on crime," "change," "drain the swamp" etc.
Special interests pay very close attention and are actively involved in policy-making and contribute to political campaigns
Politicians allocate funds towards special interests
"In fiscal year (FY) 2013, Americans consumed 12 million tons of refined sugar, with the average price for raw sugar 6 cents per pound higher than the average world price. That means, based on 24 billion pounds of refined sugar use at a 6-cents-per-pound U.S. premium, Americans paid an unnecessary $1.4 billion extra for sugar. That is equivalent to more than $310,000 per sugar farm in the United States"
Source: Heritage Foundation
"Washington, D.C., doesn't have many farms, or farmers. Yet thousands of residents in and around the nation's capital receive millions of dollars every year in federal farm subsidies...lawyers, lobbyists and at least one psychologist collected nearly $342,000 in taxpayer farm subsidies between 2008 and 2011...[also] Gerald Cassidy, the founder of one of Washington's most powerful lobbying firms, Cassidy & Associates; Charlie Stenholm, a former congressman; and Chuck Grassley, a Republican senator from Iowa; [and former] Secretary of Agriculture Tom Vilsack..."
And yet, each individual pays maybe $1-2 a year in higher prices for sugar
Difficult to mobilize voters to petition to end the sugar subsidy to save $1
Sugar producers stand to lose a billion dollars
Sugar PACs that contribute thousands to key lawmakers
People often commit the nirvana fallacy and view the government as a unicorn
“The Munger test”: replace “the government should do [X]” with:
“Politicians elected by rationally ignorant voters and capturable by lobbying by special interests should suggest to autonomous bureaucrats, to [do X]”
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
Esc | Back to slideshow |