+ - 0:00:00
Notes for current slide
Notes for next slide

4.4 — Factor Markets

ECON 306 · Microeconomic Analysis · Fall 2020

Ryan Safner
Assistant Professor of Economics
safner@hood.edu
ryansafner/microF20
microF20.classes.ryansafner.com

Returning to Firms

  • Recall a firm uses technology that buys inputs, transforms them, and sells output q=f(k,l)

    • We classified inputs into the factors of production: land, labor, capital
  • We assumed fixed factor prices

    • show up in total cost =wL+rK
  • Where do they come from? Factor markets

Circular Flow

Firms’ Payments to Factors are Income To Households

Income Type Amount (2016) Percent
Salaries and wages $7217 Bn 68.45%
Taxable pensions and annuities $694 Bn 6.58%
Partnership and S corporation net income $629 Bn 5.97%
Capital gains less losses $621 Bn 5.89%
Business net income $389 Bn 3.69%
Taxable Social Security benefits $286 Bn 2.71%
Taxable IRA distributions $258 Bn 2.45%
Ordinary dividends $254 Bn 2.41%
Total rental and royalty net income $98 Bn 0.93%
Taxable interest $97 Bn 0.92%

Source: Tax Foundation, 2018

Firms’ Payments to Factors are Income To Households

Source: Tax Foundation, 2018

Supply and Demand in Factor Markets

  • The price of a factor is governed by the same market forces as output:

  • Supply of Factor: willingness of factor owners to accept and sell/rent their services to firms

    • landowners, workers, capitalists, resource owners, suppliers
  • Demand for Factor: willingness of firms to pay for/hire factor services

Factor Market Prices and Opportunity Costs

  • Factor price represents opportunity cost of hiring a factor for an alternative use
    • Firms not only pay for direct use of a factor, but also indirectly for not using it in an alternate process!

Factor Market Prices and Opportunity Costs

  • Example: a producer of hammers buys steel, pays (the opportunity cost) for "taking" the steel away from alternative uses

Factor Market Prices and Opportunity Costs

  • Example: e.g. salary for a skilled worker must be high enough to keep them at their current firm, and not be attracted to other firms/industries

Example Factor Market: Labor Markets

  • Empirically, about 70% of total cost of production comes from labor

  • We’ll focus just on the market for labor as an example factor market

  • Can do the same for any factor market

    • (e.g. capital, land, materials, etc.)

Labor Market for a Competitive Firm

Derived Demand in Factor Markets

  • Demand for factors is a "derived demand":

    • Firm only demands inputs to the extent they contribute to producing sellable output
  • Firm faces a tradeoff when hiring more labor, as more labor ΔL creates:

    1. Marginal Benefit: Increases output and thus revenue
    2. Marginal Cost: Increases costs

Marginal Revenue Product (of Labor)

  • Hiring more labor increases output (i.e. labor's MPL)
    • Recall: MPL=ΔqΔL, where q is units of output

Marginal Revenue Product (of Labor)

  • Hiring more labor increases output (i.e. labor's MPL)

    • Recall: MPL=ΔqΔL, where q is units of output
  • Additional output generates (i.e. labor's MR(q))

    • Recall: MR(q)=ΔR(q)Δq, where R(q) is total revenue

Marginal Revenue Product (of Labor)

  • Hiring more labor increases output (i.e. labor's MPL)

    • Recall: MPL=ΔqΔL, where q is units of output
  • Additional output generates (i.e. labor's MR(q))

    • Recall: MR(q)=ΔR(q)Δq, where R(q) is total revenue
  • Hiring more labor, on the margin, generates a benefit, called the marginal revenue product of labor, MRPL: MRPL=MPLMR(q)
    • i.e. the number of new products a new worker makes times the revenue earned by selling the new products

Marginal Revenue Product for Competitive Firms

  • This is the Firm's Demand for Labor:

MRPL=MPLMR(q)

  • For a firm in a competitive (output) market, firm's MR(q)=p, hence:

MRPL=MPLp

where p is the price of the firm's output

Marginal Revenue Product for Competitive Firms

MRPL=MPLp

  • Marginal benefit of hiring labor, MRPL falls with more labor used

    • production exhibits diminishing marginal returns to labor!
  • Choke price for labor demand: price too high for firm to purchase any labor

A Competitive Factor Market

  • If the factor market is competitive, labor supply for an individual firm is perfectly elastic at the market price of labor (w)

A Brief Digression on Economic Rents I

  • Recall market supply is the minimum willingness to accept, the minimum price necessary to bring a resource to market (its opportunity cost)

  • But all (equivalent) labor is paid the market wage, w determined by market labor supply and labor demand

A Brief Digression on Economic Rents II

  • Some workers would have accepted a job for less than w

  • These inframarginal workers earn economic rent in excess of what is needed to bring them into the market (their opportunity cost)

A Brief Digression on Economic Rents III

  • Consider a factor (such as land) for which the supply is perfectly inelastic (e.g. a fixed supply)

  • Then the entire value of the land is economic rent!

  • The less elastic the supply of a factor, the more economic rent it generates!

Labor Supply and Firm's Demand for Labor

  • We've seen a falling MRPL, the marginal benefit of hiring labor

  • Marginal cost of hiring labor, w, remains constant

    • so long as firm is not a big purchaser (has no market power) in the labor market

Labor Supply and Firm's Demand for Labor

  • At low amounts of labor, marginal benefit MRPL>w marginal cost

  • Firm will hire more labor

Labor Supply and Firm's Demand for Labor

  • At high amounts of labor, marginal benefit MRPL<w marginal cost

  • Firm will hire less labor

Labor Supply and Firm's Demand for Labor

  • Firm hires L optimal amount of labor where w=MRPL

  • i.e. marginal cost of labor = marginal benefit of labor

Labor Supply and Firm's Demand for Labor

Labor Supply and Firm's Demand for Labor

  • If market supply of labor decreases, wages increase & firms hire fewer workers (and vice versa)

Example

Example: Victoria’s Tours is a travel company that offers guided tours of nearby mountain biking trails. Its marginal revenue product of labor is given by MRPL=1,00040l, where l is the number of tour-guide weeks it hires and MRPL is measured in dollars per tour-guide week. The going market wage for Victoria’s Tours is $600 per tour-guide week.

  1. What is the optimal amount of labor for Victoria’s Tours to hire?

  2. At and above what market wage would Victoria’s Tours not want to hire anyone?

  3. What is the most labor Victoria’s Tours would ever hire, given its marginal revenue product?

Labor Demand for a Monopoly

Labor Demand for Competitive vs. Monopolist Firm

  • Recall a firm's demand for labor: MRPL=MPLMR(q)

  • A firm in a competitive output industry has its MR(q)=p

    • So we saw its Labor Demand, MRPL=MPLp

Labor Demand for Competitive vs. Monopolist Firm

  • Recall if firm is a monopolist in its output industry, its MR(q)<p

    • So its Labor Demand, MRPL=MRPLMR(q)
  • Since MR(q)<p, a monopoly in its output industry will always have lower demand for labor, and thus, hire less labor than a competitive firm

    • Monopoly produces less output, so wants fewer inputs!

Labor Demand for Competitive vs. Monopolist Firm

  • This is about the competitiveness of the output or "downstream" market

  • Here, both competitive firm and monopolist in downstream markets face the same perfectly elastic labor supply

    • We've assumed no market power in the input or "upstream" market (for labor)
  • We next consider market power in the upstream (labor) market...

Monopsony Power

Monosony

  • What if the firm has market power in a factor market?

  • Consider extreme example: monopsony: a factor market with a single buyer

Monosony and Market Supply of Labor

  • Market power in hiring labor implies that the firm faces the whole market factor supply curve for labor

  • Market supply is upward sloping

  • Factor (inverse) supply describes minimum price workers are willing to accept to work

Monosony and Market Supply of Labor

  • As firm chooses to hire more L, must raise wages on all workers to hire them

Monosony and Market Supply of Labor

  • As firm chooses to hire more L, must raise wages on all workers to hire them

  • Output effect: increased cost from increased number of workers

Monosony and Market Supply of Labor

  • As firm chooses to hire more L, must raise wages on all workers to hire them

  • Output effect: increased cost from increased number of workers

  • Price effect: increased cost from raising wage for all workers

Monopsony and Marginal Cost of Labor I

  • If monopsonist wants to hire more labor, ΔL, its labor cost C(L) would change by:

ΔC(L)=wΔL + LΔw

Monopsony and Marginal Cost of Labor I

  • If monopsonist wants to hire more labor, ΔL, its labor cost C(L) would change by:

ΔC(L)=wΔL + LΔw

  • Output effect: increases number of labor hired (ΔL) times wage w per worker

Monopsony and Marginal Cost of Labor I

  • If monopsonist wants to hire more labor, ΔL, its labor cost C(L) would change by:

ΔC(L)=wΔL + LΔw

  • Output effect: increases number of labor hired (ΔL) times wage w per worker

  • Price effect: raises wage per worker (Δw) on all workers hired (L)

Monopsony and Marginal Cost of Labor I

  • If monopsonist wants to hire more labor, ΔL, its labor cost C(L) would change by:

ΔC(L)=wΔL + LΔw

  • Output effect: increases number of labor hired (ΔL) times wage w per worker

  • Price effect: raises wage per worker (Δw) on all workers hired (L)

  • Divide both sides by ΔL to get Marginal Cost of Labor, MC(L):

ΔC(L)ΔL=MC(L)=w+ΔwΔLL

Monopsony and Marginal Cost of Labor I

  • If monopsonist wants to hire more labor, ΔL, its labor cost C(L) would change by:

ΔC(L)=wΔL + LΔw

  • Output effect: increases number of labor hired (ΔL) times wage w per worker

  • Price effect: raises wage per worker (Δw) on all workers hired (L)

  • Divide both sides by ΔL to get Marginal Cost of Labor, MC(L):

ΔC(L)ΔL=MC(L)=w+ΔwΔLL

  • Compare: supply for a price-taking firm is perfectly elastic: ΔwΔL=0, so we saw MC(L)=w!

Monopsony and Marginal Cost of Labor II

  • If we have a linear inverse supply function for labor of the form w=a+bL
    • a is the choke price (intercept)
    • b is the slope

Monopsony and Marginal Cost of Labor II

  • If we have a linear inverse supply function for labor of the form w=a+bL
    • a is the choke price (intercept)
    • b is the slope
  • Marginal cost of labor again is defined as: MC(L)=w+ΔwΔLL

Monopsony and Marginal Cost of Labor II

  • If we have a linear inverse supply function for labor of the form w=a+bL
    • a is the choke price (intercept)
    • b is the slope
  • Marginal cost of labor again is defined as: MC(L)=w+ΔwΔLL
  • Recognize that ΔwΔL is the slope, b, (riserun)

Monopsony and Marginal Cost of Labor II

  • If we have a linear inverse supply function for labor of the form w=a+bL
    • a is the choke price (intercept)
    • b is the slope
  • Marginal cost of labor again is defined as: MC(L)=w+ΔwΔLL
  • Recognize that ΔwΔL is the slope, b, (riserun)

MC(L)=w+(b)LMC(L)=(a+bL)+bLMC(L)=a+2bL

Monopsony and Marginal Cost of Labor IV

w(L)=a+bLMC(L)=a+2bL

  • Marginal cost of labor starts at same intercept as Supply (average cost of labor) (a) with twice the slope (2b)

Note: If these past few slides have sounded familiar, this is the exact same process by which we derived a monopolist’s marginal revenue curve!

Monopsony's Hiring Decisions

  • Optimal quantity is where MC=MR
    • Firm's MC(L)=MRPL

Monopsony's Hiring Decisions

  • Optimal quantity is where MC=MR

    • Firm's MC(L)=MRPL
  • Monopsonist faces entire market supply

    • Can lower wages as low as workers’ minimum WTA (Supply)

Monopsonist’s Hiring Decisions

  • Optimal quantity is where MC=MR

    • Firm's MC(L)=MRPL
  • Monopsonist faces entire market supply

    • Can lower wages as low as workers' minimum WTA (Supply)
  • Compared to a competitive labor market (Lc,wc), monopsonist hires fewer workers and pays them lower wages (Lm,wm)

    • Creates deadweight loss

Monopsony Depends on Price Elasticity of Supply

The more (less) elastic labor supply, the less (more) monopsony power

Less Elastic Labor Supply Curve

More Elastic Labor Supply Curve

Monopoly Power in Labor Markets: Unions

Monopoly Power in Labor Markets: Unions

  • If seller/s of labor (workers) has market power, can act like a monopolist on the labor market

  • Example: A labor union

  • Faces entire market demand for labor, and thus its marginal revenue curve too

  • Acts like a monopolist, restricts Lu<Lc to push up wu>wc

The Problem of Bilateral Monopoly

  • What if both sides of the market have market power?

    • A downstream monopsonist buyer vs. an upstream monopolist seller
  • This is the problem of bilateral monopoly

  • Find out more in my industrial organization course

    • One solution is vertical integration: merge into a single firm across both markets

Paused

Help

Keyboard shortcuts

, , Pg Up, k Go to previous slide
, , Pg Dn, Space, j Go to next slide
Home Go to first slide
End Go to last slide
Number + Return Go to specific slide
b / m / f Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode
c Clone slideshow
p Toggle presenter mode
t Restart the presentation timer
?, h Toggle this help
Esc Back to slideshow