2.4 — Costs of Production — Class Notes
Contents
Wednesday, September 23, 2020
Overview
Today we cover costs before we put them together next class with revenues to solve the firm’s (first stage) profit maximization problem. While it seems we are adding quite a bit, and learning some new math problems with calculating costs, we will practice it more next class, when put together with revenues.
Slides
Appendix
The Relationship Between Returns to Scale and Costs
There is a direct relationship between a technology’s returns to scaleIncreasing, decreasing, or constant
and its cost structure: the rate at which its total costs increaseAt a decreasing rate, at an increasing rate, or at a constant rate, respectively
and its marginal costs changeDecreasing, increasing, or constant, respectively
. This is easiest to see for a single input, such as our assumptions of the short run (where firms can change \(l\) but not \(\bar{k})\):
\[q=f(\bar{k},l)\]
Constant Returns to Scale:
Decreasing Returns to Scale
Increasing Returns to Scale
Cobb-Douglas Cost Functions
The total cost function for Cobb-Douglas production functions of the form \[q=l^{\alpha}k^{\beta}\] can be shown with some very tedious algebra to be:
\[C(w,r,q)=\left[\left(\frac{\alpha}{\beta}\right)^{\frac{\beta}{\alpha+\beta}} + \left(\frac{\alpha}{\beta}\right)^{\frac{-\alpha}{\alpha+\beta}}\right] w^{\frac{\alpha}{\alpha+\beta}} r^{\frac{\beta}{\alpha+\beta}} q^{\frac{1}{\alpha+\beta}}\]
If you take the first derivative of this (to get marginal cost), it is:
\[\frac{\partial C(w,r,q)}{\partial q}= MC(q) = \frac{1}{\alpha+\beta} \left(w^{\frac{\alpha}{\alpha+\beta}} r^{\frac{\beta}{\alpha+\beta}}\right) q^{\left(\frac{1}{\alpha+\beta}\right)-1}\]
How does marginal cost change with increased output? Take the second derivative:
\[\frac{\partial^2 C(w,r,q)}{\partial q^2}= \frac{1}{\alpha+\beta} \left(\frac{1}{\alpha+\beta} -1 \right) \left(w^{\frac{\alpha}{\alpha+\beta}} r^{\frac{\beta}{\alpha+\beta}}\right) q^{\left(\frac{1}{\alpha+\beta}\right)-2}\]
Three possible cases:
- If \(\frac{1}{\alpha+\beta} > 1\), this is positive \(\implies\) decreasing returns to scale
- Production function exponents \(\alpha+\beta < 1\)
- If \(\frac{1}{\alpha+\beta} < 1\), this is negative \(\implies\) increasing returns to scale
- Production function exponents \(\alpha+\beta > 1\)
- If \(\frac{1}{\alpha+\beta} = 1\), this is constant \(\implies\) constant returns to scale
- Production function exponents\(\alpha+\beta = 1\)
Example (Constant Returns)
Let \(q=l^{0.5}k^{0.5}\).
\[\begin{align*} C(w,r,q)&=\left[\left(\frac{0.5}{0.5}\right)^{\frac{0.5}{0.5+0.5}} + \left(\frac{0.5}{0.5}\right)^{\frac{-0.5}{0.5+0.5}}\right] w^{\frac{0.5}{0.5+0.5}} r^{\frac{0.5}{0.5+0.5}} q^{\frac{1}{0.5+0.5}}\\ C(w,r,q)&= \left[1^{0.5}+1^{-0.5} \right]w^{0.5}r^{0.5}q^{0.5}\\ C(w,r,q)&= w^{0.5}r^{0.5}q^{1}\\ \end{align*}\]
Consider input prices of \(w=\$9\) and \(r=\$25\):
\[\begin{align*}C(w=10,r=20,q)&=9^{0.5}25^{0.5}q \\ & =3*5*q\\ & =15q\\\end{align*}\]
That is, total costs (at those given input prices, and technology) is equal to 15 times the output level, \(q\):
Marginal costs would be
\[MC(q) = \frac{\partial C(q)}{\partial q} = 15\]
Average costs would be
\[MC(q) = \frac{C(q)}{q} = \frac{15q}{q} = 15\]
Example (Decreasing Returns)
Let \(q=l^{0.25}k^{0.25}\).
\[\begin{align*} C(w,r,q)&=\left[\left(\frac{0.25}{0.25}\right)^{\frac{0.25}{0.25+0.25}} + \left(\frac{0.25}{0.25}\right)^{\frac{-0.25}{0.25+0.25}}\right] w^{\frac{0.25}{0.25+0.25}} r^{\frac{0.25}{0.25+0.25}} q^{\frac{1}{0.25+0.25}}\\ C(w,r,q)&= \left[1^{0.5}+1^{-0.5} \right]w^{0.5}r^{0.5}q^{2}\\ C(w,r,q)&= w^{0.5}r^{0.5}q^{2}\\ \end{align*}\]
If \(w=9\), \(r=25\):
\[\begin{align*}C(w=10,r=20,q)&=9^{0.5}25^{0.5}q^2 \\ & =3*5*q^2\\ & =15q^2\\\end{align*}\]
Marginal costs would be
\[MC(q) = \frac{\partial C(q)}{\partial q} = 30q\]
Average costs would be
\[AC(q) = \frac{C(q)}{q} = \frac{15q^2}{q} = 15q\]